Maximum-profit equilibrium: monopoly Essay

1 - Maximum-profit equilibrium: monopoly Essay introduction. If an industry is to be classed as one of pure ( or hone ) competition, there are said to be two basic requirements.It is argued that when these two conditions are satisfied, the consequence is, for the single house, a demand curve that is virtually horizontal & # 8212 ; i.e. , absolutely or about absolutely elastic with regard to monetary value. The house is free to sell every bit much or every bit small as it pleases at a market monetary value over which it has no control.

We will write a custom essay sample on
Maximum-profit equilibrium: monopoly Essay
or any similar topic specifically for you
Do Not Waste
Your Time
SEND

By clicking "SEND", you agree to our terms of service and privacy policy. We'll occasionally send you account related and promo emails.

More Essay Examples on

Very few real-life houses find themselves in this place. This is because ( so the present chapter argues ) of failure to fulfill one or both of the two basic demands for perfect competition. In existent life, that is, the figure of houses may be excessively ( large/small ) for perfect competition. In add-on, the merchandises sold by the assorted houses may be ( indistinguishable among all firms/differentiated from one house to the following ) .

( I ) many little houses, ( two ) all selling indistinguishable pro-ducts:

little: differentiated from one house to the following.

2. These two features & # 8212 ; a too-small figure of Sellerss and/or the distinction of the viing merchandises & # 8212 ; are said to hold “ monopolistic ” effects.

Notice that this word “ monopolistic ” does non intend that the houses involved are monopolies. The conventional definition of a monopoly state of affairs is this: ( I ) merely one house in the industry, and ( two ) no close replacements available for the merchandise of that one-firm industry.

Except in a few particular countries such as public utilities, instances come closing echt monopoly are about as hard to happen as are instances of perfect competition. Monopoly is a sort of utmost case of competitory imperfectness. Economist Edward H. Chamberlin, who did much to develop the thoughts set out in the first portion of this chapter, argued that the typical real-life state of affairs is one of “ monopolistic competition. ” Each house finds that it must think with the competition of close replacement merchandises ( so that it is non a monopoly ) ; and yet its state of affairs is non that of pure or perfect competition.

The word “ monopolistic ” is used because it is argued that there is one monopoly-like feature to be found in all such instances of monopolistic or imperfect competition. less than absolutely elastic with regard to monetary value & # 8212 ; i.e. , it is “ atilt ” instead than horizontal.

3. If the figure of selling houses is little, the name given to the ensuing state of affairs is

If the figure of selling houses is big, but competition is non perfect, this must be ( in the linguistic communication of the text ) a state of affairs of oligopoly: many differentiated Sellerss.

In its gap subdivisions, this text chapter describes the fortunes of progressive or monopolistic competition. But it does non try to research these state of affairss in any existent item. Alternatively, after its introductory lineation, the chapter turns to an scrutiny of the profit-maximising behaviour of a monopoly house. Analytically, this monopoly instance is unquestionably easier than the alleged “ intermediate ” instances & # 8212 ; those non absolutely competitory, and yet non wholly monopolistic. It would be unwise to undertake these more intricate instances before holding mastered the simple thoughts of monopoly pricing.

Even the footings and diagrams involved in a description of monopoly pricing may look complicated at first. Yet the basic thought involved is simple. The monopoly house is assumed to act so as to “ maximise its net income ” & # 8212 ; which is precisely what the house in pure ( or hone ) competition was assumed.The monopoly house merely operates in instead different fortunes.

To reexamine the basic thoughts of “ net income maximization ” :

1. “ Maximizing net income ” means doing every bit much money as supply conditions will allow.

2. To “ maximise net income, ” there must be something the house can make that will act upon its net income. There must be some variable which changes net income, and which the house can command.

3. This chapter assumes that the monopoly house can command the measure it sells, merely as the house in pure ( or hone ) competition can make. ( In existent life, this control is at best indirect and uncomplete ; there are other and more complex determinations to be made. But this chapter tackles a simple instance. ) So the variable which the monopoly house can command is its gross revenues measure: it looks for the peculiar gross revenues measure that will maximise its net income.

4. The monopoly house is assumed to hold control over its gross revenues measure because it knows the demand agenda for its merchandise & # 8212 ; i.e. , it knows the gross revenues measure that goes with each and any monetary value it might bear down.

5. From this demand agenda, it is easy to develop a gross agenda ( Entire Revenue being measure sold multiplied by monetary value per unit ) & # 8212 ; i.e. , a agenda demoing gross associated with each possible measure sold.

6. The house must cognize besides the Entire Cost of each and any end product measure. By conveying together the gross and cost agendas, it can so place that end product measure at which the surplus of gross over cost ( net income ) is greatest. ( And it can state the monetary value to bear down for this Maximum-profit end product merely by confer withing the demand agenda one time once more. )

To reiterate, the indispensable thing to hold on about this sequence of thoughts is that it is simple. It is merely when the monopoly house ‘s profit-maximising “ equilibrium place ” ( with regard to gross revenues end product and monetary value ) is outlined in fringy footings that it may look complicated. But these fringy footings are indispensable analytic tools when one moves on to more complex state of affairss. Hence the accent on Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost in the text chapter and in the reappraisal inquiries which follow.

4. Columns ( 1 ) and ( 2 ) of Study Guide Table 1 represent a demand agenda. This agenda has been computed or estimated by a house as bespeaking the measures it can sell daily at assorted monetary values.

Table 1

This house must run under conditions of ( perfect/imperfect ) competition, since as the end product to be sold additions, monetary value ( remains constant/must be reduced ) .

5. We treat the first two columns of Table 1 as stand foring a monopoly house ‘s demand agenda. Our undertaking is to find what monetary value the monopolizer will bear down, and what end product it will bring forth and sell & # 8212 ; if its aim is Maximum-profit.

O. Column ( 3 ) of Table 1 shows Total Revenue & # 8212 ; monetary value times measure. Complete the four spaces in this column.

Then usage Columns ( 2 ) and ( 3 ) figures to exemplify Total Revenue on Study Guide Fig. 1 & # 8212 ; i.e. , show Entire Revenue associated with assorted end product measures. Join the points with a smooth curve. Disregard momently the TC curve already drawn on Fig. 1.

& # 1089 ; . Notice that this demand agenda becomes price-inelastic, when monetary value is sufficiently lowered & # 8212 ; specifically, when monetary value reaches $ ( 8/7/6/5/4 ) .

The graph of Columns ( 1 ) and ( 2 ) of Table 2 is already drawn on Fig.1 as a Entire Cost curve ( TC ) . ( Mark the curve you drew in inquiry 5 as TR, to separate it from the cost curve. )

It is now possible to see at one time why the profit-maximizing procedure outlined here is a simple one. The house is making nil more than to seek for the end product at which the perpendicular distance between TR and TC is greatest. This distance, for any end product, is ( fixed cost/price/profit or loss ) . ( If TR is above TC, it is net income ; if TC is above, it is loss. ‘ So it is preferred to look for “ greatest perpendicular distance ” with & # 1043 ; & # 1044 ; above TC. The greatest distance with & # 1043 ; & # 1057 ; on top Markss the maximum-possible loss, which is slightly less desirable as an operating place. )

6. Figure 1 is excessively little to bespeak rapidly the precise Maximum-profit place. But even a glimpse is sufficient to bespeak that this best-possible place is about i.45/65/85 ) units of end product.

The house can be thought of as bit by bit increasing its end product and gross revenues, hesitating at each addition to see if its net income place is improved. Each excess unit of end product brings in

a little more gross ( provided demand has non vet moved to the price-inelastic scope ) ; and each excess unit incurs a little more cost. The house ‘s net income place is improved if this little sum of excess gross ( exceeds/is equal to/is less than ) the little sum of excess cost.

More elegantly put, end product should be increased, for it will give an addition in net income, if Fringy Revenue ( MR ) ( exceeds/is equal to/is less than ) Fringy Cost ( MC ) . The house should cut back its end product and gross revenues if it finds that MR ( exceeds/is equal to/is less than ) MC.

And so the “ in-balance ” place is where MR is ( less than/equal to/greater than ) MC.

7. A more careful development of the Marginal Revenue thought is needed. Column ( 4 ) in Table 1 shows the excess figure of units sold if monetary value is reduced. Column ( 5 ) shows excess gross ( positive or negative ) accruing from that monetary value decrease. Complete the spaces in these two columns to familiarise yourself with the significances involved.

8. The general profit-maximizing regulation is: Expand your end product until you reach the end product degree at which MR = MC & # 8212 ; and halt at that point.

The profit-maximising regulation for the house in pure ( or hone ) competition: P = MC. This is nil but a peculiar case of the MR = MC regulation. It is assumed in pure ( or hone ) competition that the demand curve confronting the single house is absolutely horizontal, or absolutely price- ( elastic/inelastic } . That is, if market monetary value is $ 2, the house receives ( less than $ 2 /exactly $ 2/more than $ 2 ) for each excess unit that it sells. In this particular instance, MR ( excess gross per unit ) is ( greater than/the same thing as/less than ) monetary value per unit ( which could be called Average Revenue, or gross per unit ) . So in pure ( or hone ) competition, P == MC and MR = MC are two ways of stating the same thing.

9. In imperfect competition, the house ‘s demand curve is & # 8212 ; and things are different. From review of the figures in Table 1 [ comparison Columns ( 1 ) and ( 6 ) ] , it is apparent that with such a demand curve, MR at any peculiar end product is ( greater than/the same thing as/less than ) monetary value for that end product.

Why is this so? Suppose, at monetary value $ 7, you can sell 4 units ; at monetary value $ 6, 5 units. Grosss associated with these two monetary values are severally $ 28 and $ 30. Fringy Gross from selling the 5th unit is consequently $ ( 2/5/6/7/28/30 ) . It is the difference in gross obtained as a consequence of sel

ling the one excess unit. Why merely $ 2—when the monetary value at which that fifth unit sold was 86? Because to sell that 5th unit, monetary value had to be reduced. And that lowered monetary value applies to all 5 units. The first 4, which once sold at $ 7, now conveying merely $ 6. On this history, gross takes a whipping of $ 4. You must deduct Sns $ 4 from the $ 6 which the fifth unit brings in. This leaves a net addition in gross of $ 2—Marginal Revenue.

10. To return to the lucks of the house in Tables 1 and 2: The tabular arraies do non supply sufficient unit-by-unit item to demo the exact Maximum-profit end product degree. But Table 1 indicates that between gross revenues end products of 63 and 71, MR is $ 1.63. The MR figures fall as gross revenues are expanded, so that the $ 1.63 would use near the center of this scope, say at end product 67. It would be slightly higher between 63 and 66 ; slightly lower between 68 and 71.

Similarly, MC ( Table 2 ) would be SI.60 at end product of about 67 units. So the Maximum-profit place would fall really near to 67 units produced and sold per period.

To sell this end product, the house would bear down a monetary value ( see Table 1 ) of approximately 8 ( 7 ‘5.75/4/1.60 ) . Its Entire Revenue [ expression for nearby figures in Column ( 3 ) ] would be approximately $ ( 380/580/780 ) . Its Entire Cost ( Table 2 ) would be approximately ^ ( 310/510/710 ) , go forthing net income per period of about $ 70.

$ 5.75 ; $ 380 ; $ 310.

The text notes that in geometric footings Fringy Gross can be depicted as the incline of the Total Revenue curve.

Tills can be illustrated by looking more carefully at the Total Revenue curve you have drawn in Study Guide Fig. 1. Study Guide Fig. 2 shows an expansion of a little section of that curve: that portion of the curve between end product measures of 25 and 31. If 25 units are sold, the monetary value is 810 and Entire Revenue is $ 250. This is point A on Fig. 2. If monetary value is reduced to $ 9, that increases gross revenues by 6 units, from 25 units to 31 units. Thus Total Revenue becomes $ 279 ( 31 multiplied by $ 9 ) . So, if the house reduces monetary value from $ 10 to $ 9, in consequence it moves from point A to point B.

Figure 2 ‘s heavier, curving line is the smooth curve used to fall in points A and B. It is an estimate of the points that would be obtained if we had measure and gross information on monetary values such as ‘59.90, S9.SO, and so on.

There is besides a consecutive line ( the thin line ) fall ining A and B. It is close to the likely true Total Revenue curve although it is non likely to be the exact curve.

Alternatively of dropping from monetary value $ 10 all the manner to $ 9, suppose we had moved merely to ( state ) $ 9.60. That would hold produced ( approximately ) a 2-unit addition in measure demanded. In this manner, we would travel closer to the true MR figure than our old 6-unit estimate supplied. In Fig. 2 footings, we would be traveling from A merely to

D, non from A to B. Notice carefully that the consecutive line ( the thin line ) fall ining A to D becomes a ( better/poorer ) estimate of the presumed true Total Revenue curve than was the instance when the points involved were A and B.

In amount, the closer we move point B to indicate A ( for illustration, if we make it D instead than B ) , the closer the incline figure comes to being a step of the true MR figure. Strictly talking, we have true MR ( the rate of alteration in gross as measured in footings of 1-unit end product alterations ) merely when the line whose incline is being measured and used to bespeak MR is really tangent to the Total Revenue curve.

In its near-closing subdivision Bygones and Margins, the text chapter emphasizes that if a house is puting its monetary value and end product harmonizing to MR = MC rules, it will ignore Fixed Cost.

Quiz: Multiple Choice

1. If a house ‘s Marginal Revenue exceeds its Marginal Cost, Maximum-profit regulations require that house to ( 1 ) increase its end product in both perfect and imperfect competition ; ( 2 ) increase its end product in perfect but non needfully in imperfect competition ; ( 3 ) increase its end product in progressive but non needfully in perfect competition ; ( 4 ) lessening its end product in both perfect and imperfect competition ; ( 5 ) addition monetary value, non end product, in both perfect and imperfect competition.

2. Whenever a house ‘s demand curve is horizontal or “ absolutely elastic, ” so ( 1 ) the house can non be runing under conditions of perfect competition ; ( 2 ) the profit-maximising regulation of MR-equal-to-MC does non use ; ( 3 ) monetary value and Marginal Revenue-must be one and the same ; ( 4 ) monetary value and Fringy Cost must be one and the same ; ( 5 ) none of the above is needfully right.

3. A basic difference between the house in perfect ( or pure ) competition and the monopoly house, harmonizing to economic analysis, is this: ( 1 ) The perfect rival can sell every bit much as he wishes at some given monetary value, whereas the monopolizer must take down his monetary value whenever he wishes to increase the sum of his gross revenues by any important sum ;

( 2 ) the monopolizer can ever bear down a monetary value that brings him a significant net income, whereas the perfect rival can ne’er gain such a net income ; ( 3 ) the snap of demand confronting the monopolizer is a higher figure than the snap of demand confronting the perfect rival ; ( 4 ) the monopolizer seeks to maximise net income, whereas the perfect rival ‘s regulation is to compare monetary value and Average Cost ; ( 5 ) none of the above.

4. “ Oligopoly ” means ( 1 ) the same thing as imperfect competition ; ( 2 ) a state of affairs in which the figure of viing houses is big but the merchandises differ somewhat ; ( 3 ) a state of affairs in which the figure of viing houses is little ;

( 4 ) that peculiar status of imperfect competition which is merely removed from monopoly, irrespective of the figure of houses or type of merchandise: ( 5 ) none of these.

5. When a monopoly house seeking to maximise its net incomes has reached its “ equilibrium place, ” so ( 1 ) monetary value must be less than Fringy Cost ; ( 2 ) monetary value must be equal to Marginal Cost ; ( 3 ) monetary value must he greater than Fringy Cost ; ( 4 ) monetary value may be equal to or below Fringy Cost, but non above it ; ( 5 ) none of the above is needfully right since equilibrium does non necessitate any peculiar relation between monetary value and Marginal Cost.

6. To explicate why imperfect competition is far more prevailing than perfect competition, the text lays considerable accent upon the followers: ( 1 ) the fact that Marginal Revenue is less than monetary value ; ( 2 ) the inclination of Marginal Cost to go on to fall over significant degrees of end product produced ; ( ( ) the temperament of houses to seek to maximise the net income they can derive from gross revenues ; ( 4 ) the inclination of Marginal Cost to lift after some peculiar degree of end product produced has been reached ; ( 5 ) the fact that big houses now typically produce many different merchandises, therefore squashing smaller houses out of their markets.

7. Among the five statements below, one must be false with regard to any house runing under conditions of imperfect competition. Which one? ( 1 ) The figure of viing Sellerss offering similar ( although differentiated ) merchandises can be big. ( 2 ) Other houses may sell merchandises

which are indistinguishable or about indistinguishable with this house ‘s merchandise. ( 3 ) The figure of viing Sellerss offering similar ( although differentiated ) merchandises can be little. ( 4 ) The house ‘s Marginal Revenue will be less than the monetary value it obtains. ( 5 ) The demand curve confronting the house can be absolutely horizontal.

8. A degree of end product for a house at which Marginal Cost had risen to equality with monetary value would ( 1 ) be a profit-maximising end product degree in both pure ( or hone ) competition and imperfect competition ; ( 2 ) be a profit-maximising end product degree in pure ( or hone ) competition but non in imperfect competition ; ( 3 ) non be a profit-maximising end product degree either in perfect or in imperfect competition ; ( 4 ) be a profit-maximising end product degree in imperfect competition but non in pure ( or hone ) competition ; ( 5 ) decidedly be a profit-maximising end product degree in imperfect competition, but might or might non be in pure ( or hone ) competition.

9. A house in conditions of progressive competition which finds itself at an end product degree where Marginal Cost has risen to equality with monetary value, and which wants to maximise its net income, ought to ( 1 ) increase its end product ; ( 2 ) alteration ( either addition or lessening ) its monetary value but non its end product ; ( 3 ) maintain both monetary value and end product at their present degrees ; ( 4 ) increase its monetary value ; ( 5 ) possibly do any of the above & # 8212 ; information furnished is deficient to state.

10. The kernel of the general regulation for maximising net incomes given in the text chapter is that a house should put its monetary value, or its end product, as follows: put its ( 1 ) monetary value at a degree where the surplus over the minimum-possible degree of Average Cost is at its upper limit ; ( 2 ) end product at a degree where the excess production cost ensuing from the last unit produced merely peers the excess gross brought in by that last unit ; ( 3 ) monetary value at the highest degree which the traffic will bear ; ( 4 ) monetary value at a degree merely equal to Marginal Cost ( presuming that Marginal Cost would lift with any addition in end product ) ; ( 5 ) end product at a degree where Average Cost is at a lower limit.

11. A house would be designated as a monopoly, harmonizing to the definition conventionally used by economic experts, in any state of affairs where ( 1 ) the house ‘s Marginal Revenue exceeds the monetary value it charges at all degrees of end product ( other than the first unit sold ) ; ( 2 ) the house ‘s Marginal Revenue is less than the monetary value it charges at all degrees of end product ( other than the first unit sold ) ; ( 3 ) the house has at least some grade of control over the monetary value that it can bear down ; ( 4 ) the net income earned by the.firm significantly exceeds the competitory rate of return, after proper allowance has been made for hazard undertaken ; ( 5 ) there is no other house selling a close replacement for the merchandise of this house.

12. The Fringy Revenue ( MR ) associated with any given point on a house ‘s demand curve will be related to the snap of demand at that point ( with regard to monetary value ) as follows:

( 1 ) When demand is inelastic, MR will be negative in value ;

( 2 ) when demand is elastic, MR will be negative in value ;

( 3 ) when demand is inelastic, MR will be zero in value ; ( 4 )

when demand is elastic, MR will be zero in value ; ( 5 ) .VR of monopoly or imperfect competition. The AR line is Aver-is ever positive in value ( although below monetary value ) irrespective age Revenue & # 8212 ; in other words, it is monetary value gettable per unit. of snap, except at the point or part of unit snap.

Haven’t Found A Paper?

Let us create the best one for you! What is your topic?

By clicking "SEND", you agree to our terms of service and privacy policy. We'll occasionally send you account related and promo emails.

Haven't found the Essay You Want?

Get your custom essay sample

For Only $13.90/page

Eric from Graduateway Hi there, would you like to get an essay? What is your topic? Let me help you

logo